Short Time WorkEdit
Short time work is a policy instrument designed to cushion workers and firms when demand narrows, by trimming hours rather than laying people off and by providing wage top-ups to partially compensate for lost income. It is intended to keep the employer–employee relationship intact, preserve firm-specific skills, and shorten the eventual recovery period by lowering hiring and training costs once the economy picks up again. While used most prominently in continental Europe, variants exist in other advanced economies, each with country-specific rules and funding arrangements. The core idea is simple: in a downturn, share the pain temporarily through reduced hours, with the public sector or the unemployment insurance system stepping in to retain a portion of workers’ earnings, so that workers can return to full-time work when demand returns.
In practice, short time work operates as a structured bridge between a downturn and a rebound. Employers request approval to reduce hours for eligible workers, and employees receive compensation for the lost hours, usually funded through unemployment insurance or a general public funds pool, sometimes with a partial employer contribution. The arrangement is typically time-limited and contingent on the firm’s continuing operation and maintenance of core staff, with an emphasis on preserving training and knowledge that would be costly to replace after a downturn ends. The policy is designed to be temporary, targeted, and performance-oriented rather than a permanent subsidy for payrolls.
Overview
Definition and purpose
- Short time work allows firms to reduce the working hours of employees during a downturn while the government supplements a portion of wages to keep workers attached to their jobs. The aim is to avoid a sharp rise in unemployment and to preserve human capital that would be costly to rebuild when conditions improve. See for example Kurzarbeit in Germany and similar programs in other economies.
Key features
- Hours reduction rather than permanent layoffs
- Partial wage replacement to sustain income and morale
- Funding shared by employers, workers, and the state (often via unemployment insurance or general revenue)
- Requirements to retain staff, limit duration, and, in some cases, invest in training or re-skilling
- Sunset clauses and regular reviews to ensure the program remains narrowly targeted
Variations by country
- Different systems emphasize different funding shares, eligibility rules, and interaction with the broader welfare state. In some places, the government pays a larger share of wage replacement; in others, the program hinges more on payroll or unemployment insurance contributions. See Germany and United Kingdom for large-scale historical uses of similar ideas.
Rationale from a market-oriented perspective
- By avoiding abrupt layoffs, short time work reduces the destruction of firm-specific capital, minimizes long-term unemployment, and speeds a return to normal output. It is presented as a lighter touch form of stabilization that complements rather than crowds out private market adjustment.
Mechanisms
Eligibility and application
- Firms facing a temporary decline in demand apply to participate, demonstrating the downturn’s expected duration and the need to preserve core operations. Workers must be in employment contracts eligible for the program.
Hours and wage replacement
- Hours are reduced in a programmed schedule, with the government or unemployment fund replacing a portion of the lost wages. The exact replacement rate varies by country and program design, but the intent is to maintain a meaningful portion of earnings to sustain household stability while providing a real incentive to return to full-time work when possible.
Funding and costs
- The program is financed through a mix of unemployment insurance, general revenue, and sometimes employer contributions. The cost is intended to be temporary and targeted, rather than an open-ended subsidy.
Training and retention
- In many implementations, employers are expected to maintain training arrangements and to re-hire workers to full hours as demand recovers. Training provisions help prevent skill erosion and improve matching when labor demand rebounds.
Oversight and performance
- Governments often require reports on usage, outcomes, and sunset triggers. The design is meant to deter abuse, ensure that subsidies flow to genuine downturns, and protect taxpayers from inefficient spending.
Economic rationale
Stabilizing demand and preserving human capital
- Short time work reduces the effective drop in consumer income during a recession, which supports household consumption and helps keep small businesses afloat. By preserving the employer–employee relationship, it reduces the risk that workers lose firm-specific skills and networks, making the eventual recovery faster and less costly.
Efficiency and structural adjustment
- While some critics worry about delaying necessary reallocation, proponents argue that most downturns are cyclical rather than structural, and that preserving trained workers reduces the cost and time of re-hiring and re-training when demand returns. The program is designed as a backstop, not a permanent entitlement.
Fiscal considerations and taxpayer accountability
- The right-of-center case for short time work emphasizes cost control, sunset provisions, and performance requirements. When well-designed, it lowers the overall cost of downturns by reducing unemployment benefits, fewer long-term welfare transfers, and less disruption to the tax base. Critics who fear fiscal burdens point to the need for clear exit paths and caps on duration and spending.
Comparisons with alternative tools
- Proponents view short time work as superior to blanket wage subsidies or broad-based stimulus for preserving productive capacity, because it is targeted to downturns and directly maintains employer–employee relationships. Critics sometimes argue that subsidies for hiring or payroll can distort allocation or delay needed restructuring; supporters counter that short time work is narrowly focused on keeping existing resources and skills together during temporary lulls.
History and implementations
Germany and the Kurzarbeit model
- Germany’s Kurzarbeit program is the most cited example of short time work. It has been used repeatedly to ride through economic downturns, including crises in the late 2000s and the COVID-19 shock. The structure typically involves firm-level agreements to reduce hours, with the state providing wage top-ups for a portion of the lost earnings. The system is designed to scale with the severity of the downturn and to unwind as economic activity recovers. See Kurzarbeit and Germany.
The United Kingdom and other advanced economies
- Several economies have employed similar work-sharing arrangements during downturns, with the specifics tailored to national welfare systems and labor markets. In the UK, for example, temporary furlough-like mechanisms supported workers while employers retained them on payrolls, reflecting a parallel philosophy to short time work. See United Kingdom.
The United States and other jurisdictions
- In the United States, some states operate short-time compensation programs or similar work-sharing approaches that allow partial wage replacement and hour reductions. While not as centralized as some European models, these programs share the core aim of preserving employment relationships during recessions. See United States and Unemployment insurance.
Controversies and debates
Efficiency vs. distortion
- A common debate centers on whether short time work preserves inefficient firms or outdated employment structures. Advocates argue that the costs of prolonged layoffs—lost skills, longer rehiring times, and larger scarring effects—outweigh the temporary distortions created by hour reductions. Critics claim that any ongoing subsidy risks propping up uncompetitive arrangements and delaying necessary adjustments.
Moral hazard and neutrality
- Critics worry that workers and firms may rely on subsidies rather than adjusting hours, wages, or operations. Proponents counter that when the program is clearly time-limited, tightly targeted, and conditioned on retention and training, moral hazard is constrained and the welfare benefits of avoiding mass unemployment are substantial.
Fiscal sustainability and fairness
- The argument against frequent or broad use centers on tax burdens and intergenerational cost. Proponents of a conservative frame emphasize discipline: spending should be temporary, transparent, and offset by reforms elsewhere, with fair distribution between taxpayers, workers, and firms.
Reallocation vs. retention of capital
- A longstanding tension in labor policy is between preserving current employment and enabling faster reallocation toward sectors with stronger growth. Short time work aims to tilt the balance toward retention of productive human capital when downturns are temporary, arguing that the risk of losing skilled workers to rivals or to long unemployment is a larger drag on long-run growth than the risk of occasional inefficiencies under temporary subsidies.
Design features and best practices
Time-limited and sunset-enabled
- Effective short time work programs include explicit expiry dates or automatic review points, with a clear path to end or broaden the program as conditions change.
Targeted and demand-responsive
- The most credible designs tie eligibility to a measurable downturn in demand and to firm commitments to maintain the core workforce and to invest in training or upskilling where appropriate.
Shared funding and accountability
- A balanced structure uses a mix of government funding and employer contributions, with caps on total costs and reporting to ensure transparency and value for taxpayers.
Exit strategy and post-recovery planning
- Good designs link the wind-down of subsidies to a plan for rehiring or reallocation, minimizing the risk of abrupt discontinuities when demand rebounds.
Safeguards against abuse
- Oversight mechanisms reduce the likelihood of abuse, ensure that savings from the program are not redirected to unrelated subsidies, and confirm that wage top-ups reflect genuine hours reductions.